I thought this was an intriguing question, with some contradictory responses in this thread that make it even more interesting. Following is an attempt at providing a quantitative answer.
perfect_play.jpg
There is a lot going on here. I considered four sets of rules: 6D, S17, DOA, DAS, SPL3 as a baseline shown in purple, with the four colored curves indicating the four possible combinations of including (or not) RSA and/or LS. The x-axis indicates a particular assumed penetration. The y-axis indicates the overall expected return, in percentage of flat-bet unit wager, from long-term play, that is, repeatedly playing from the top of each shuffled shoe down to the cut card at the corresponding penetration.
This is a combination of CA and simulation, using the count.exe tool (binary and source code available on
GitHub, so anyone can review or even reproduce these results). For each of the four rule sets, I simulated 10,000 shoes to 5.5/6 penetration, for each round evaluating the pre-round EV assuming CDZ- strategy for that exact composition of depleted shoe. From this, we can evaluate any candidate intermediate penetration from 0/6 (i.e., reshuffle after each round, at x=0, which we can verify agrees with the full-shoe EV reported by e.g. the strategy.exe CA tool at the above link) to 5.5/6 (note the constant behavior of each curve beyond this point is thus an artifact of my stopping each simulated shoe there).
We might think 10,000 simulated shoes (or roughly 530,000 rounds) is a hopelessly small sample; but keep in mind that each sample is not just an
outcome of each corresponding round but rather each sample is itself an
exact expected value of the return from the corresponding current depleted shoe. The gray curves flanking each colored curve indicate the 95% (roughly 2-sigma) confidence interval for our estimate of the
overall expected return played to a given penetration.
The baseline purple curve corresponds to my choice of rules in a
2013 analysis where I made the following comment: "... perfect play yields an expected return of only -0.2333%. In other words, even equipped with a laptop at the table, the house still has an advantage! This is not as surprising as it sounds; since we are focusing on playing efficiency, we are assuming flat betting. This merely emphasizes the point that, in shoe games, accurate betting strategy is more important than varying playing strategy."
In that analysis, I assumed 4.5/6 penetration; the -0.2333% value corresponds to the x=4.5 point on the purple curve above. Widening our view with this new analysis, we can see that:
1. Even pushing deeper to 5.5/6, those baseline rules still don't yield a flat-betting player advantage.
2. Even allowing both resplit of aces and (late) surrender requires 5/6 penetration to even start to see a flat-betting advantage.
3. Although RSA and LS individually have comparable effects on full-shoe EV (i.e., the green and blue curves closely agree at x=0), with deeper penetration surrender is more advantageous than RSA.
Finally, the "wiggle" near x=0 is interesting. Granted, it's an unrealistic region of penetration (i.e., we aren't dealing more than one, but less than half dozen rounds between shuffles), but I don't yet understand what's happening there.
These results were calculated in about a laptop-day of CPU time; I'm wondering if there has been similar past analysis of "penetrating computer perfect play" (more precisely, any analysis based on strategy maximizing EV for each pre-round depleted shoe), e.g. supporting any of the claims in earlier comments in this thread, that would be interesting to compare with?
Bookmarks